The Surprising Importance of Grades
Skip to content
Economics Apr 5, 2010

The Surprising Importance of Grades

Sending signals in the job market

Pupil receives A grade on paper

RaStudio via iStock

Based on the research of

Brendan Daley

Brett Green

Since the 1970s, economic theorists have wrestled with the problem of education. Aside from learning and self-improvement, their models led them to conclude that the primary reason we go to school is to prove to potential employers that we would be good employees, mostly by getting as much education as possible.

Their models said nothing about other types of information, such as grades, letters of recommendation, and other measures of “reputation.” This led economists to predict that students of varying abilities would tend to end their education at different points in the journey from high school to a Ph.D., and that the more capable students would pursue more education to differentiate themselves from less capable students

In reality, there are many factors that influence how many degrees people tack on to their résumés. But despite the limitations of the models, attempts to understand how ability is communicated through educational attainment have led to a general mathematical understanding of the way that one party conveys or signals information to another. It is a framework that can be applied to everything from online rating systems to car warranties. Now Brett Green, an assistant professor of finance at the Kellogg School of Management, and Brendan Daley, an assistant professor at Duke University, have extended this model of signaling to include something economists typically ignore: the implications of grades.

When Green talks about grades, he does not mean only the kind that students receive on their report cards. He includes many kinds of information about a person or entity that come from an independent evaluation of quality, which includes seller ratings on eBay, bond ratings handed out by Moody’s, and product reviews on CNET or Amazon.com.

Sending Signals
The traditional notion of signaling in economic theory is that, in the context of asymmetric information—which means I have information that you do not, such as knowledge about my likely value as an employee—I have to engage in costly activities to prove my value to you. Those efforts could include the pursuit of more education, extracurricular activities, or any other endeavors that cost me time and energy. The idea is that, if I am smart and capable, these things are easier for me to attain than if I am dull and incompetent—thus, they are credible signals about my abilities.

From this premise, economists who have studied signaling have concluded that, when signaling their quality to potential employers, high-quality candidates will pile on as many degrees, volunteer hours, and positions in student government as needed to distinguish themselves from the less-capable. But that is not what happens in the real world.

In the real world, grades matter, or at least they do to the extent that they accurately measure of a student’s ability. Previous research has suggested that information conveyed by grades is irrelevant, because if capable and less-capable students were perfectly sorting themselves out by the level of costly education they were able to attain, any additional “noisy” information can be safely discarded.

“In the real world, grades matter, or at least they do to the extent that they accurately measure of a student’s ability.”

When grades are incorporated into the old models, their predictions change. Green and Daley’s model, which adds the independent assessments they call grades to the costly signals that can be transmitted in instances of asymmetric information, yields many explanations of everyday phenomena in markets. Its primary implication is that when grades are added to the information an employer has about a potential employee, both high- and low-quality potential employees tend to pool in the middle of the achievement field. In other words, because employers have an additional assessment of a candidate’s value (grades), the high-quality students do not have to spend as much time and energy earning graduate degrees or participating in extracurricular activities to distinguish themselves from low-quality students, They can partially rely on their superior grades to demonstrate their abilities.

The Upside of Grades
Green and Daley’s finding that capable and not-so-capable students tend to pool in the middle of a distribution of potential levels of educational attainment—that is, many more of both high and low capability will stop at a bachelor’s or master’s degree than would have been expected absent the information contained in grades—stands in sharp contrast to results derived from older models of signaling, in which the only things that were considered were costly signals like time spent in school. One implication of this finding is that when grades are absent from the information a potential employer has—as with business schools for which either school administration or the student body has decided to conceal grades on the grounds that it creates a more collegial atmosphere—students must get more education or participate in more extracurricular activities in order to signal their value to employers.

“One policy implication for schools with grade non-disclosure policies is that you’ll see people expending more resources to signal their ability than would be the case if you had grades,” says Green. Such behavior reduces students’ welfare, leads to overall inefficiency, and in general suggests that grades are a good thing because they enhance transparency in a market, he adds.

Incorporating grades into the model changes one other major counterintuitive prediction from the traditional models: that the seller’s reputation does not matter. In previous models, just as employers disregarded information about students’ grades, so too did buyers completely disregard their prior assessments of a seller’s type—in other words, their reputation. In these models, even if receivers were 99.9% certain that the sender of information—the seller—was high quality, the sender would expend the same amount of costly resources signaling as he or she would if the receivers’ initial beliefs were much less favorable. In Green and Daley’s model, having a good reputation leads to exactly the opposite of what the old models predicted.

A good example of this prediction are automobile warranties. Green points out that Hyundai offers a much better warranty than Honda because Honda has a better reputation than the upstart Hyundai, even though the latest models of both companies cars get similar reliability ratings (or grades) from reviewers like Consumer Reports. In traditional signaling theory, the expectation would be that any car company with a good record of reliability would offer the maximum warranty it could because, as a costly signal, this would let consumers know just how reliable the manufacturer believed its cars were.

In reality, Honda offers a less comprehensive warranty than Hyundai, which accords with Green and Daley’s model. Their prediction is that the “grades” of Honda’s cars, which have accumulated over the years from ratings services like Consumer Reports and Edmunds, result in Honda’s not having to expend as much capital on warranties. Consumers have already ascertained, through independent means, the quality of their cars. In other words, sellers with higher reputations need not signal as vigorously as sellers whose reputations are not as strong.

Green believes that the explosion of channels for grades on the Internet has changed how both consumers and sellers solve the problem of asymmetric information. “There’s just so much information out there on the Internet that to think that the only information you have is what the person selling you the car wants you to have is ridiculous,” says Green. “Gathering information from the Internet is cheap and easy and changes the way markets function.”

Featured Faculty

Member of the Department of Finance faculty between 2009 and 2012

About the Writer
Christopher Mims is a freelance writer based in Gainesville, Florida.
About the Research

Daley, Brendan, and Brett Green. 2009. Market Signaling with Grades. Working paper, Kellogg School of Management.

Read the original

Most Popular This Week
  1. One Key to a Happy Marriage? A Joint Bank Account.
    Merging finances helps newlyweds align their financial goals and avoid scorekeeping.
    married couple standing at bank teller's window
  2. Take 5: Yikes! When Unintended Consequences Strike
    Good intentions don’t always mean good results. Here’s why humility, and a lot of monitoring, are so important when making big changes.
    People pass an e-cigarette billboard
  3. How Are Black–White Biracial People Perceived in Terms of Race?
    Understanding the answer—and why black and white Americans may percieve biracial people differently—is increasingly important in a multiracial society.
    How are biracial people perceived in terms of race
  4. Will AI Eventually Replace Doctors?
    Maybe not entirely. But the doctor–patient relationship is likely to change dramatically.
    doctors offices in small nodules
  5. Entrepreneurship Through Acquisition Is Still Entrepreneurship
    ETA is one of the fastest-growing paths to entrepreneurship. Here's how to think about it.
    An entrepreneur strides toward a business for sale.
  6. Take 5: Research-Backed Tips for Scheduling Your Day
    Kellogg faculty offer ideas for working smarter and not harder.
    A to-do list with easy and hard tasks
  7. How to Manage a Disengaged Employee—and Get Them Excited about Work Again
    Don’t give up on checked-out team members. Try these strategies instead.
    CEO cheering on team with pom-poms
  8. Which Form of Government Is Best?
    Democracies may not outlast dictatorships, but they adapt better.
    Is democracy the best form of government?
  9. What Went Wrong at AIG?
    Unpacking the insurance giant's collapse during the 2008 financial crisis.
    What went wrong during the AIG financial crisis?
  10. The Appeal of Handmade in an Era of Automation
    This excerpt from the book “The Power of Human" explains why we continue to equate human effort with value.
    person, robot, and elephant make still life drawing.
  11. 2 Factors Will Determine How Much AI Transforms Our Economy
    They’ll also dictate how workers stand to fare.
    robot waiter serves couple in restaurant
  12. When Do Open Borders Make Economic Sense?
    A new study provides a window into the logic behind various immigration policies.
    How immigration affects the economy depends on taxation and worker skills.
  13. Why Do Some People Succeed after Failing, While Others Continue to Flounder?
    A new study dispels some of the mystery behind success after failure.
    Scientists build a staircase from paper
  14. Sitting Near a High-Performer Can Make You Better at Your Job
    “Spillover” from certain coworkers can boost our productivity—or jeopardize our employment.
    The spillover effect in offices impacts workers in close physical proximity.
  15. How the Wormhole Decade (2000–2010) Changed the World
    Five implications no one can afford to ignore.
    The rise of the internet resulted in a global culture shift that changed the world.
  16. What’s at Stake in the Debt-Ceiling Standoff?
    Defaulting would be an unmitigated disaster, quickly felt by ordinary Americans.
    two groups of politicians negotiate while dangling upside down from the ceiling of a room
  17. What Happens to Worker Productivity after a Minimum Wage Increase?
    A pay raise boosts productivity for some—but the impact on the bottom line is more complicated.
    employees unload pallets from a truck using hand carts
  18. Immigrants to the U.S. Create More Jobs than They Take
    A new study finds that immigrants are far more likely to found companies—both large and small—than native-born Americans.
    Immigrant CEO welcomes new hires
  19. How Has Marketing Changed over the Past Half-Century?
    Phil Kotler’s groundbreaking textbook came out 55 years ago. Sixteen editions later, he and coauthor Alexander Chernev discuss how big data, social media, and purpose-driven branding are moving the field forward.
    people in 1967 and 2022 react to advertising
  20. 3 Traits of Successful Market-Creating Entrepreneurs
    Creating a market isn’t for the faint of heart. But a dose of humility can go a long way.
    man standing on hilltop overlooking city
Add Insight to your inbox.
More in Economics