Where Does Capitalism Go Next?
Skip to content
Strategy Economics Policy Jul 5, 2022

Where Does Capitalism Go Next?

A conversation on “creative destruction,” growth, and designing a more equitable capitalist future.

two people look out over a city

Michael Meier

Based on insights from

Benjamin F. Jones

Philippe Aghion

What will the future of capitalism look like?

One of the central questions facing many economists is how economies can continue to grow and innovate in ways that are sustainable over the long term.

For Philippe Aghion, a professor at the College de France and at INSEAD, it helps to think about the problem in terms of “creative destruction”—the process by which new products and ideas replace older ones. Aghion was recently at Kellogg to deliver the Nancy M. Schwartz Memorial Lecture. During his visit, he spoke with Kellogg’s Ben Jones, a professor of strategy, to discuss innovation, competition, and designing a more equitable capitalist future.

This conversation has been edited for length and clarity.

Ben JONES: What do you mean when you use the term “creative destruction” in relation to innovation?

Philippe AGHION: The term refers to three things: First, innovation is a cumulative process—you stand on the shoulders of predecessors. Second, you innovate because you have incentives to innovate. And third, new innovations tend to displace old technologies.

Part of what’s interesting about this is that you have a contradiction at the heart of the growth process. On the one hand, you need innovation to motivate innovation. But on the other hand, there is this temptation by yesterday’s innovators to prevent subsequent innovators because they don’t want themselves to be subject to creative destruction.

JONES: Right. A lot of existing players don’t want to be displaced, and when they’re powerful, they are going to use their political and regulatory influence to prevent their own destruction.

When you think of innovation through this lens, you realize that innovation isn’t simply about being creative. You have to think about the market and the political institutions that allow this fluid destruction and reallocation. It’s easy to see why countries prevent this from happening.

A well-functioning market without interference can allow for people to start something new. When Amazon or Walmart comes in, they’re knocking out a lot of smaller mom-and-pop retail. These are powerfully painful experiences, but you hope that in a well-functioning, fluid market, those owners and workers can reallocate to more productive firms and the market will push consumers toward those firms. But in a system where that doesn’t happen, that’s where you can get into this middle-income trap.

AGHION: Exactly. While the U.S. and the UK have systems to manage creative destruction, other countries like China and Korea are catch-up innovators. They developed because they imitated technology, so competition has not been so crucial. During their catching-up phase, the large firms that developed not only inhibited entry and innovation by smaller firms, but also used the government to prevent the transition towards institutions that favored frontier innovation. The big conglomerates become a barrier to competition.

In terms of regulating capitalism, governments have to choose their tools. For example, if they overtax the capital income of firms, they will discourage innovators. Innovation allows people to get to the top income brackets. But because of creative destruction, it’s also a force of social mobility. You could argue that this is a “good” source of income inequality. Whereas an entry barrier like lobbying is a bad source, because it reduces entry, social mobility, and growth while it increases global inequality.

JONES: A different way to think about the problem of regulation is through the lens of market failures—or where the market gets things right or wrong. Market failures come in two forms: One, the market is doing too much of something, like we probably produce too much carbon because no private sector player has to account for pollution. So the costs for polluting are wrong. But the market can also fail by doing too little. And innovation and science are areas where markets do too little.

You can often motivate tax policy by saying, “we want to ideally tax the things that the market does too much of and then subsidize the things where the market does too little.” Of course, we don’t necessarily get it right in the U.S., but we do have considerable infrastructure in place, from the research and development tax credit, to funding basic science, to government grants and federal research agencies.

Building on that idea, how would you bring companies and governments and civil-society organizations into the climate-change conversation?

Education and competition policy are as effective at making growth more inclusive as taxation.

— Philippe Aghion

AGHION: It’s true that growth is the source of the increasing temperature. If you look at China and India, the takeoff of growth coincides with the takeoff in CO2 emissions. But would you go back to the pre-1820s? No.

The state has ways to redirect change towards greener technologies with carbon offsets, but also subsidies for clean innovation and smart industrial policy.

But civil society also has a role to play. Consumers can force firms to innovate greener, particularly in more competitive environments. Because even if my company is not virtuous, I may lose my customers to you if you are virtuous.

JONES: I think innovation and R&D is the solution to climate change. It’s a tale of two global public goods. On the negative side, it doesn’t matter where greenhouse gas emissions come from; they cause warming everywhere.

On the positive side, new ideas can help globally. The way we’re going to solve climate change is when everyone adopts better technologies. That’s only going to happen when they’re cheaper. And whatever country you’re in, you benefit.

AGHION: Speaking of market failures, COVID revealed some of the weaknesses of capitalism, which are different from one country to another. While the U.S. is the best model of innovation—with its basic research funding, venture capital, and institutional investors—it might not be the best social model. During COVID in the U.S., a lot of people lost their jobs and their health insurance and fell into poverty when they needed support. We didn’t see anything like this in Scandinavia or Germany. Which raises a big question for debate: Can you be innovative like the U.S. and protective and inclusive like Denmark?

I think there are policies that can make you both more innovative and more inclusive. For example, when you lose your job in Denmark, for three years, you get 90 percent of your salary. The state helps you find a new job and they retrain you.

Another example is education. We know there are many “lost Einsteins,” or very smart children born to poor families that cannot give them a proper education and aspirations to become inventors. Now, what’s very interesting is that Finland had a reform in 1970 to make education high quality and very inclusive. With this inclusive education system, they overcame the “lost Einsteins” phenomenon. When you do that, you manage to have a more innovative economy because more people can become inventors and it’s more inclusive.

JONES: There are features of markets that are great for innovation, but the idea that the market left to itself is going to get it right is far off. If we starve the pipeline of future innovators by not offering high-quality access to K-12 education in the United States, these lost Einsteins are really lost. And that’s on public policy to get that right.

AGHION: Education and competition policy are as effective at making growth more inclusive as taxation.

Here’s another example: competition. We know that competition policy in the U.S. has not adapted to the digital era. We are obsessed with market share and market definition, and not looking at whether mergers and acquisitions prevent future entry and innovation. During the IT revolution, you had the emergence of superstar firms: Google, Amazon, Walmart. At first, they were a booster of growth, but then, through mergers and acquisitions, they became hegemonic and discouraged entry and innovation.

Now, suppose you reform competition policy, like what the Biden administration tried to do last year. Then you will make the economy more innovative. I don’t know if it will be effective, but hopefully, you could reverse that trend.

And remember, creative destruction induces social mobility. So if you manage to revamp competition policy, you will make the economy more innovative and more inclusive. And that makes me optimistic that we can improve capitalism.

Featured Faculty

Gordon and Llura Gund Family Professor of Entrepreneurship; Professor of Strategy

Most Popular This Week
  1. 3 Things to Keep in Mind When Delivering Negative Feedback
    First, understand the purpose of the conversation, which is trickier than it sounds.
  2. Podcast: Workers Are Stressed Out. Here’s How Leaders Can Help.
    On this episode of The Insightful Leader: You can’t always control what happens at work. But reframing setbacks, and instituting some serious calendar discipline, can go a long way toward reducing stress.
  3. What Went Wrong at Silicon Valley Bank?
    And how can it be avoided next time? A new analysis sheds light on vulnerabilities within the U.S. banking industry.
    People visit a bank
  4. How Are Black–White Biracial People Perceived in Terms of Race?
    Understanding the answer—and why black and white Americans may percieve biracial people differently—is increasingly important in a multiracial society.
    How are biracial people perceived in terms of race
  5. Will AI Eventually Replace Doctors?
    Maybe not entirely. But the doctor–patient relationship is likely to change dramatically.
    doctors offices in small nodules
  6. Leaders, Don’t Be Afraid to Admit Your Flaws
    We prefer to work for people who can make themselves vulnerable, a new study finds. But there are limits.
    person removes mask to show less happy face
  7. Which Form of Government Is Best?
    Democracies may not outlast dictatorships, but they adapt better.
    Is democracy the best form of government?
  8. What Went Wrong at AIG?
    Unpacking the insurance giant's collapse during the 2008 financial crisis.
    What went wrong during the AIG financial crisis?
  9. What Happens to Worker Productivity after a Minimum Wage Increase?
    A pay raise boosts productivity for some—but the impact on the bottom line is more complicated.
    employees unload pallets from a truck using hand carts
  10. At Their Best, Self-Learning Algorithms Can Be a “Win-Win-Win”
    Lyft is using ”reinforcement learning” to match customers to drivers—leading to higher profits for the company, more work for drivers, and happier customers.
    person waiting for rideshare on roads paved with computing code
  11. When You’re Hot, You’re Hot: Career Successes Come in Clusters
    Bursts of brilliance happen for almost everyone. Explore the “hot streaks” of thousands of directors, artists and scientists in our graphic.
    An artist has a hot streak in her career.
  12. Why Do Some People Succeed after Failing, While Others Continue to Flounder?
    A new study dispels some of the mystery behind success after failure.
    Scientists build a staircase from paper
  13. Immigrants to the U.S. Create More Jobs than They Take
    A new study finds that immigrants are far more likely to found companies—both large and small—than native-born Americans.
    Immigrant CEO welcomes new hires
  14. Take 5: Tips for Widening—and Improving—Your Candidate Pool
    Common biases can cause companies to overlook a wealth of top talent.
  15. Why Well-Meaning NGOs Sometimes Do More Harm than Good
    Studies of aid groups in Ghana and Uganda show why it’s so important to coordinate with local governments and institutions.
    To succeed, foreign aid and health programs need buy-in and coordination with local partners.
  16. How Has Marketing Changed over the Past Half-Century?
    Phil Kotler’s groundbreaking textbook came out 55 years ago. Sixteen editions later, he and coauthor Alexander Chernev discuss how big data, social media, and purpose-driven branding are moving the field forward.
    people in 1967 and 2022 react to advertising
  17. How Peer Pressure Can Lead Teens to Underachieve—Even in Schools Where It’s “Cool to Be Smart”
    New research offers lessons for administrators hoping to improve student performance.
    Eager student raises hand while other student hesitates.
  18. How Much Do Campaign Ads Matter?
    Tone is key, according to new research, which found that a change in TV ad strategy could have altered the results of the 2000 presidential election.
    Political advertisements on television next to polling place
  19. Take 5: How Fear Influences Our Decisions
    Our anxieties about the future can have surprising implications for our health, our family lives, and our careers.
    A CEO's risk aversion encourages underperformance.
More in Strategy