When Does One Good Deed Deserve Another?
Skip to content
Leadership Policy Jan 1, 2009

When Does One Good Deed Deserve Another?

The calculus of reciprocity

Based on the research of

Madan M. Pillutla

Deepak Malhotra

J. Keith Murnighan

Listening: Interview with Keith Murnighan
download
0:00 Skip back button Play Skip forward button 16:22

Rationality suggests that trust should build slowly and that people should proceed cautiously when building a relationship. But what if you only have one chance to decide whether to trust someone? In that case, caution might be a poor choice: it can be perceived as distrust and thus reduce the possibility of engendering trust. To investigate this, J. Keith Murnighan of the Kellogg School of Management, with Madan M. Pillutla (London Business School) and Deepak Malhotra (Harvard Business School), performed two experiments using the Trust Game. In the Trust Game, a player (Player 2) decides whether and how much to reciprocate when given money by an anonymous person (Player 1), with both players knowing that however much Player 1 sends, Player 2 gets triple that amount.

Game theory, which analyzes the best courses of action in competitive situations, predicts that Player 1 will send no money because of the risk of getting nothing back, even though sending nothing sacrifices the benefits that come from tripling the amount sent. For both players to obtain these benefits, Player 1 must bear the risks, with rational models of trust development suggesting that initial risks taken be relatively small. If the acts of trust are too small, however, then they may not be recognized as trust and they might even anger Player 2s who expect Player 1s to see the benefits of sending more.

Precipitous acts of trust, which on the surface may seem irrational, can accelerate trust development.Earlier studies of the relationship between trust and reciprocity often used Prisoner’s Dilemma games in which the rational, short-term strategy is for a prisoner to confess. This leads to a better outcome regardless of their partner’s choice. But if both use this logic and confess, both prisoners go to jail for a much longer period than they would if they both kept quiet. Keeping quiet leads to the most efficient outcome and depends on the prisoners trusting each other. When the players know they will see each other in the future, the cooperative outcome becomes more likely.

Trust and Reciprocity

In Pillutla, Malhotra, and Murnighan’s experiments, players had only one interaction, giving them no opportunity for reputation building. Participants, all Player 2s, were told that an anonymous player (Player 1) could send them any portion of a fixed amount of money ($10 or $20), and they would actually receive three times the money sent. Thus, if Player 1 sent $5, Player 2 received $15. Player 2 then decided how much, if anything, to return to Player 1. The investigators experimentally manipulated the amounts (from $2 to the entire amount) sent by Player 1.

Feelings of obligation or indebtedness might compel Player 2 to return some money, especially if Player 1 chose to send all or most of their money. By setting up the experiments so Player 2 could receive more or less than the amount Player 1 retained, the authors could directly examine the influence of the amount sent on feelings of obligation as well as actual reciprocity.

Player 1s in the Trust Game face a difficult choice: the more they send, the more they risk, because Player 2 is not required to return any money. Thus, Player 1s must balance their risks with their expectations that Player 2s will reciprocate; if Player 2s do not reciprocate, any money sent is lost. Murnighan and his co-authors speculated that with maximal trust—sending everything—Player 2s would feel a strong sense of obligation, reciprocity would be the greatest, and non- reciprocation would be least likely. After the experiment, participants responded to a questionnaire concerning their feelings about Player 1s, the amount they returned, and the characteristics they attributed to Player 1s.

Greater Trust, Greater Returns

Both experiments showed that reciprocity increased as the money sent increased: sending more increased reciprocity. When Player 2s could achieve equal outcomes (because Player 1s sent them enough), 80 percent of the recipients returned just enough to equalize the two players’ final outcomes. Although maximal trust actually did not increase the likelihood of reciprocity, it did increase the chance that—when players did reciprocate—they would return an amount that equalized returns. And when Player 1s only sent small amounts, recipients frequently returned nothing. Feelings of obligation completely explained the relationship between the amounts sent and returned: larger amounts sent led to greater feelings of obligation and greater returns. Also, after playing the Trust Game, Player 2s viewed Player 1s who sent more money as more trusting and more intelligent.

The results contrast markedly with rational prescriptions for trust development which favor caution. Instead, these findings indicate that precipitous acts of trust, which on the surface may seem irrational, can accelerate trust development. Precipitous acts of trust do entail risk, as evidenced by the frequent instances of zero returns. According to Murnighan, “There may be too much risk and very little payoff for sending a lot of money.” Nevertheless, the amounts returned were higher for maximal and almost-maximal trust. From a societal standpoint, the authors conclude, “Sending everything maximizes joint outcomes, and, if reciprocity could be guaranteed, might increase Player 1 outcomes by as much as 50 percent.” People who exhibited more trust and took greater risks benefited more—in this case monetarily—and people who exhibited less trust and took smaller risks often missed a golden opportunity.

Featured Faculty

Member of the Department of Management & Organizations from 1996-2016

About the Writer
Bea Weaver, is a freelance writer based in Altamonte Springs, Florida.
About the Research

Pillutla, Madan M., Deepak Malhotra, and J. Keith Murnighan (2003) “Attributions of trust and the calculus of reciprocity,” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 39(5): 448-455.

Read the original

Most Popular This Week
  1. 3 Tips for Reinventing Your Career After a Layoff
    It’s crucial to reassess what you want to be doing instead of jumping at the first opportunity.
    woman standing confidently
  2. College Campuses Are Becoming More Diverse. But How Much Do Students from Different Backgrounds Actually Interact?
    Increasing diversity has been a key goal, “but far less attention is paid to what happens after we get people in the door.”
    College quad with students walking away from the center
  3. When Do Open Borders Make Economic Sense?
    A new study provides a window into the logic behind various immigration policies.
    How immigration affects the economy depends on taxation and worker skills.
  4. Which Form of Government Is Best?
    Democracies may not outlast dictatorships, but they adapt better.
    Is democracy the best form of government?
  5. Podcast: Does Your Life Reflect What You Value?
    On this episode of The Insightful Leader, a former CEO explains how to organize your life around what really matters—instead of trying to do it all.
  6. 5 Ways to Improve Diversity Training, According to a New Study
    All too often, these programs are ineffective and short-lived. But they don’t have to be.
    diversity training session
  7. How Has Marketing Changed over the Past Half-Century?
    Phil Kotler’s groundbreaking textbook came out 55 years ago. Sixteen editions later, he and coauthor Alexander Chernev discuss how big data, social media, and purpose-driven branding are moving the field forward.
    people in 1967 and 2022 react to advertising
  8. Your Team Doesn’t Need You to Be the Hero
    Too many leaders instinctively try to fix a crisis themselves. A U.S. Army colonel explains how to curb this tendency in yourself and allow your teams to flourish.
    person with red cape trying to put out fire while firefighters stand by.
  9. Immigrants to the U.S. Create More Jobs than They Take
    A new study finds that immigrants are far more likely to found companies—both large and small—than native-born Americans.
    Immigrant CEO welcomes new hires
  10. Podcast: China’s Economy Is in Flux. Here’s What American Businesses Need to Know.
    On this episode of The Insightful Leader: the end of “Zero Covid,” escalating geopolitical tensions, and China’s potentially irreplaceable role in the global supply chain.
  11. What Went Wrong at AIG?
    Unpacking the insurance giant's collapse during the 2008 financial crisis.
    What went wrong during the AIG financial crisis?
  12. What Happens to Worker Productivity after a Minimum Wage Increase?
    A pay raise boosts productivity for some—but the impact on the bottom line is more complicated.
    employees unload pallets from a truck using hand carts
  13. How Are Black–White Biracial People Perceived in Terms of Race?
    Understanding the answer—and why black and white Americans may percieve biracial people differently—is increasingly important in a multiracial society.
    How are biracial people perceived in terms of race
  14. Why Well-Meaning NGOs Sometimes Do More Harm than Good
    Studies of aid groups in Ghana and Uganda show why it’s so important to coordinate with local governments and institutions.
    To succeed, foreign aid and health programs need buy-in and coordination with local partners.
  15. How Much Do Campaign Ads Matter?
    Tone is key, according to new research, which found that a change in TV ad strategy could have altered the results of the 2000 presidential election.
    Political advertisements on television next to polling place
  16. How Experts Make Complex Decisions
    By studying 200 million chess moves, researchers shed light on what gives players an advantage—and what trips them up.
    two people playing chess
  17. Jeff Ubben Explains His “Anti-ESG ESG” Investment Strategy
    In a recent conversation with Kellogg’s Robert Korajczyk, the hedge-fund leader breaks down his unique approach to mission-driven investing.
    smokestacks, wind turbine, solar panel
  18. Why Do Some People Succeed after Failing, While Others Continue to Flounder?
    A new study dispels some of the mystery behind success after failure.
    Scientists build a staircase from paper