When Healthcare Providers Consolidate, Medical Bills Rise
Skip to content
Healthcare Policy Feb 1, 2018

When Healthcare Providers Consolidate, Medical Bills Rise

Can anything be done to rein in this expensive trend?

The impact of healthcare mergers and acquisitions on price.

Yevgenia Nayberg

Based on the research of

Cory Capps

David Dranove

Christopher Ody

What happens to your medical bills if your doctor’s practice merges with another or is acquired by a local hospital?

Add Insight
to your inbox.

In theory, this could drive down prices. After all, overhead might be lower if these groups consolidate, say, billing or records departments. Or the now-larger group might be able to negotiate lower prices on medical supplies.

But that is not what is actually happening, according to new research from the Kellogg School. Instead, prices have climbed as more and more healthcare providers have gained market power through mergers and acquisitions. And not much can be done about this.

While the consolidations create powerful healthcare conglomerates in many communities, the piecemeal nature of individual acquisition deals makes them unlikely to attract the attention of antitrust regulators, the research finds. It is only after multiple deals are done that the impact on pricing is felt—and by then, regulators are unlikely to step in.

These are the takeaways from two pieces of recent research conducted by David Dranove, a Kellogg professor of strategy, Christopher Ody, a research assistant professor of strategy at Kellogg, and Cory Capps of Bates White Economic Consulting.

“Integration is a well-known trend” among healthcare providers, Dranove says, “and hospitals often claim it will drive cost savings. But that’s difficult to document. So we thought we could look at prices to find out what’s really going on.”

Analyzing Healthcare Mergers and Acquisitions

One challenge facing researchers interested in the topic is availability of good data.

“You need data that allows you to identify which physicians were acquired by which hospital and how much the same physicians charged for the same services before and after the acquisition,” Dranove says. “That’s not always easy to get.”

Luckily, the researchers were able to get access to insurance-company data. The claims data covered about 12 percent of the US population.

“They gave it to us no strings attached,” Dranove says. “They were interested in our findings on pricing no matter which way it went.”

“Integration is a well-known trend and hospitals often claim it will drive cost savings. But that’s difficult to document.”

The researchers found that from 2007 to 2013, almost 10 percent of physician practices in the data were acquired by a hospital. Once acquired, prices for the services provided by those physicians rose an average of 14 percent.

“The rising prices are partly due to ‘mechanical elements’ of how prices are set in contracts,” with insurers, Dranove says. For example, insurers often write contracts that allow hospitals to bill more for a procedure than a physician group can. Additionally, Dranove says, “when a hospital owns a physician practice, they gain market power.”

Dranove notes that Medicare is taking initial steps to address the issue of higher post-acquisition prices—for example, preventing hospital-acquired physician groups that are not located at the hospital campus from billing like a hospital—and that private insurers will likely follow suit, to the extent that they can.

Do Healthcare Mergers Create Uncompetitive Markets?

Are there other impacts of these consolidations? Do these healthcare mergers and acquisitions give hospitals or large practitioner groups too much power within individual markets? And, if so, how likely are they to attract antitrust scrutiny by the US Department of Justice or Federal Trade Commission?

The researchers addressed these questions in a separate study.

“We wanted to document the rise of concentration in physician markets, then put our antitrust eye on it,” Dranove says.

The government considers physician markets uncompetitive if they have a high level of concentration, meaning a small number of healthcare providers delivers a large share of the healthcare in a specific community.

But regulators only scrutinize consolidation when a single proposed merger is seen as large enough to attract attention based on how consolidated the market will become if it goes through. That means that a number of mergers and acquisitions, which are small enough not to attract government attention, can eventually create a healthcare behemoth that makes a market uncompetitive.

“We wanted to document the rise of concentration in physician markets, then put our antitrust eye on it.”

This is what the researchers found often happened.

What Are the Key Issues during a Health-Insurance Antitrust Case?

David Dranove served as the Department of Justice’s economics expert in a major healthcare antitrust case last year. Ultimately, a federal judge thwarted the merger effort of giants Anthem (a Blue Cross plan operating in 14 states) and Cigna, the country’s number two and number four insurance providers. 

Dranove recently discussed the case’s biggest sticking points at a “post-mortem” of the merger hosted by Kellogg.

Dranove spoke to a key issue in the case: whether insurers reducing payments to healthcare providers is a legitimate justification for a merger provided that the insurers pass along those savings to consumers. To use his analogy: Is it OK to rob Peter (that is, medical providers) to pay Paul (consumers)?

Below is an edited excerpt of Dranove’s remarks. 

The courts make it clear that when you’re trying to answer the question of whether robbing Peter to pay Paul is a legitimate justification for a merger, you have to learn more about what’s going on in this robbery. 

First of all, are you sure the insurers are going to rob Peter? Will the merged company reduce the fees they are paying to providers? Do they have a plan to execute this? And can you quantify how much you’re going to rob Peter? Is the number big enough to offset concerns about the exercise of market power in the sale of insurance? The court was skeptical about how much Anthem planned to take from Peter and give to Paul. 

The second question is, “Do the insurers have to merge to rob Peter?” 

Executives testified at trial that the rules of the Blue Cross Association constrained some of the steps Anthem could take to reduce payments to providers. Simply put, Anthem could not absorb Cigna without violating these rules. To come into compliance, Anthem planned to take some steps that it could have taken without the merger. In other words, Anthem did not have to merge with Cigna in order to rob Peter. Again, this fed the court’s skeptical view of the merger. 

But suppose that Anthem is going to rob Peter and it has to merge to do that. The third and most interesting question is whether paying Paul justifies the robbery. If Peter is powerless, say a solo physician in a struggling practice, this hardly seems fair. But suppose Peter is a powerful hospital system whose prices are well above competitive rates. Perhaps someone should be pulling those prices down. Robbing Peter to pay Paul might then make sense. The court left this door open for future merger analyses, but given its skepticism about other aspects of the merger, it chose not to walk through. Economists would be equally hesitant, even if other aspects of the merger were on firmer ground.

Read more

Using the same insurance-claims data in 1,117 physician markets, they found that a full 22 percent of markets meet federal guidelines for uncompetitive. But only 28 percent of these high-concentration markets had an individual acquisition that would have been viewed as anticompetitive by federal authorities.

“It turns out the explanation is very simple,” Dranove says. “The way the laws are currently written and enforced, the antitrust agency is unlikely to even know about the increases in provider concentration.”

This comes down to a matter of deal frequency and size. “Deals are usually investigated for antitrust issues one transaction at a time,” he says. “These physician-group acquisitions tend to be very small, such that individually they’re not anticompetitive. Even if deals involved 10 doctors at a time, they probably wouldn’t get much attention. But collectively they can definitely be anticompetitive, over time.”

While regulators could seek to take action further down the road, they have little incentive and insufficient personnel to do so.

“The agencies don’t really have a stomach for going back and breaking up a large physician group,” Dranove says. “They’d rather stop something before it happens than break things up after the fact. The horse is already out of the barn at that point.”

What Can Be Done?

What does this mean for the quality of healthcare delivered by these increasingly large providers?

“We can’t state whether quality has improved as a result of these market dynamics,” Dranove says. “So many factors affect quality that it’s hard to study. That means our research hasn’t painted the entire picture for policymakers and agencies.”

Still, the rising prices alone are significant. And there appears to be little that can be done to improve the situation.

Dranove points out that state-based agencies might be able to regulate provider integration: “State agencies could stop acquisitions by writing legislation to prohibit them. But that probably goes too far in the other direction.”

Insurers, too, have limited power over higher pricing.

“If insurers said, ‘If you become too large we won’t do business with you,’ they’d simply be shooting themselves in the foot,” Dranove says. “The physician group would just walk away from them to another insurer, taking all the enrollees with them.”

That is not to say insurers don’t have their own market power.

“I don’t want to make it sound like we know exactly where the balance of power lies in these issues,” Dranove says. “But the market power gained through integration certainly enhances the provider side of the ledger.”

Featured Faculty

Walter J. McNerney Professor of Health Industry Management; Faculty Director of PhD Program; Professor of Strategy

About the Writer
Sachin Waikar is a freelance writer based in Evanston, Illinois.
Most Popular This Week
  1. Will AI Eventually Replace Doctors?
    Maybe not entirely. But the doctor–patient relationship is likely to change dramatically.
    doctors offices in small nodules
  2. 3 Tips for Reinventing Your Career After a Layoff
    It’s crucial to reassess what you want to be doing instead of jumping at the first opportunity.
    woman standing confidently
  3. What Happens to Worker Productivity after a Minimum Wage Increase?
    A pay raise boosts productivity for some—but the impact on the bottom line is more complicated.
    employees unload pallets from a truck using hand carts
  4. 6 Takeaways on Inflation and the Economy Right Now
    Are we headed into a recession? Kellogg’s Sergio Rebelo breaks down the latest trends.
    inflatable dollar sign tied down with mountains in background
  5. What Is the Purpose of a Corporation Today?
    Has anything changed in the three years since the Business Roundtable declared firms should prioritize more than shareholders?
    A city's skyscrapers interspersed with trees and rooftop gardens
  6. How to Get the Ear of Your CEO—And What to Say When You Have It
    Every interaction with the top boss is an audition for senior leadership.
    employee presents to CEO in elevator
  7. Why We Can’t All Get Away with Wearing Designer Clothes
    In certain professions, luxury goods can send the wrong signal.​
    Man wearing luxury-brand clothes walks with a cold wind behind him, chilling three people he passes.
  8. Why You Should Skip the Easy Wins and Tackle the Hard Task First
    New research shows that you and your organization lose out when you procrastinate on the difficult stuff.
    A to-do list with easy and hard tasks
  9. How Are Black–White Biracial People Perceived in Terms of Race?
    Understanding the answer—and why black and white Americans may percieve biracial people differently—is increasingly important in a multiracial society.
    How are biracial people perceived in terms of race
  10. Which Form of Government Is Best?
    Democracies may not outlast dictatorships, but they adapt better.
    Is democracy the best form of government?
  11. When Do Open Borders Make Economic Sense?
    A new study provides a window into the logic behind various immigration policies.
    How immigration affects the economy depends on taxation and worker skills.
  12. Why Do Some People Succeed after Failing, While Others Continue to Flounder?
    A new study dispels some of the mystery behind success after failure.
    Scientists build a staircase from paper
  13. How Has Marketing Changed over the Past Half-Century?
    Phil Kotler’s groundbreaking textbook came out 55 years ago. Sixteen editions later, he and coauthor Alexander Chernev discuss how big data, social media, and purpose-driven branding are moving the field forward.
    people in 1967 and 2022 react to advertising
  14. How Old Are Successful Tech Entrepreneurs?
    A definitive new study dispels the myth of the Silicon Valley wunderkind.
    successful entrepreneurs are most often middle aged
  15. How Offering a Product for Free Can Backfire
    It seems counterintuitive, but there are times customers would rather pay a small amount than get something for free.
    people in grocery store aisle choosing cheap over free option of same product.
  16. Immigrants to the U.S. Create More Jobs than They Take
    A new study finds that immigrants are far more likely to found companies—both large and small—than native-born Americans.
    Immigrant CEO welcomes new hires
  17. College Campuses Are Becoming More Diverse. But How Much Do Students from Different Backgrounds Actually Interact?
    Increasing diversity has been a key goal, “but far less attention is paid to what happens after we get people in the door.”
    College quad with students walking away from the center
  18. How Peer Pressure Can Lead Teens to Underachieve—Even in Schools Where It’s “Cool to Be Smart”
    New research offers lessons for administrators hoping to improve student performance.
    Eager student raises hand while other student hesitates.
More in Healthcare