How Regulating Hospital Prices Can Impact Patient Care
Skip to content
Healthcare May 10, 2021

How Regulating Hospital Prices Can Impact Patient Care

There are tangible benefits for quality of care when hospitals compete for higher-paying patients.

patients and healthcare workers in modern hospital lobby

Yevgenia Nayberg

Healthcare in the U.S. is expensive and growing ever more so. By one measure, healthcare spending had climbed to $3.8 trillion in 2019, or $11,582 per person—more than doubling since 2000.

American policymakers and patients across the political spectrum generally agree that rising healthcare prices are a concern, but the question of how to slash them has spurred contentious, headline-dominating debates. Some argue for the expansion of the government’s public healthcare option—often invoking the shorthand “Medicare for all”—which would pay hospitals and other providers substantially less for most services than private insurers currently do. Others have called on the government to regulate healthcare prices directly.

While lower prices sound appealing for consumers, Kellogg professors Amanda Starc and Craig Garthwaite wondered what the domino effects could be of legislating major changes to healthcare markets. In a new paper, coauthored with Christopher Ody, formerly a research assistant professor of strategy at Kellogg, they focus on one question in particular: Would regulating hospital prices in an effort to lower them impact the quality of the services these crucial organizations provide?

“Rising healthcare costs are certainly something we want to think about,” says Starc, an associate professor of strategy. “But from the consumer’s perspective, quality is obviously very important as well. If we change hospitals’ financial incentives, we want to think about how they’ll respond along quality dimensions.”

The researchers theorized that hospitals with a greater ability to draw high-paying, privately insured patients would offer demonstrably higher-quality services than those whose patient bases were largely publicly insured and thus paid less for those services. The reason for this, they believed: hospitals with higher-paying patients made more investments in quality as a way to differentiate themselves—and to ensure their indispensability in private insurance networks.

“From the consumer’s perspective, quality is obviously very important as well. If we change hospitals’ financial incentives, we want to think about how they’ll respond along quality dimensions.”

— Amanda Starc

The researchers’ findings suggest that their theories were right on the money. The team examined the demographics of zip codes near hospitals, which allowed them to estimate the share of privately and publicly insured patients the hospital could potentially attract. This helped them estimate the potential prices a given hospital could command for its services. The team then looked for a relationship between those potential prices and various measures of hospital quality. Importantly, while investments in quality would improve care for all patients, it would only lead to higher prices for the privately insured.

The result was a consistent pattern: across all quality measures, higher scores were associated with a higher share of potential private patients. What’s more, the researchers found evidence that hospitals that expect to court more private patients make costly investments in quality.

“This becomes an important input into the conversation that I think we’re going to have after the pandemic ends about healthcare reform,” says Garthwaite, a strategy professor and the director of Healthcare at Kellogg. “We don’t want to keep having this facile argument that high prices are high just because hospitals are getting extra profits they shouldn’t get—as opposed to recognizing that hospitals are making investments to attract patients. Those two interpretations have very different implications for what might happen in response to widespread use of price regulation.”

The Cost of Receiving High-Quality Care

To begin, the researchers had to find a way to capture the relative price-setting power of hospitals’ potential client bases. They did this by analyzing zip code–level demographics from the American Community Survey and 2010 Census, and then using a formula based on proximity to predict the share of a hospital’s patients coming from each zip code.

To quantify the actual quality of a given hospital, the researchers built six quality measures:

  • A Hospital Compare composite score, which drew from a government-run website that offers various types of datapoints on how hospitals stack up.
  • A measure that captured emergency-department wait times, which also came from government data.
  • A measure based on data from the American Hospital Association’s annual survey that measures the adoption of technology related to birth, cardiology, diagnostic imaging, radiation therapy, and transplantation.
  • A measure based on data from Medicare’s 2011 Hospital Service Area File to see which hospitals were most preferred by Medicare patients, who don’t face insurance network–based restrictions.
  • The percentage of a hospital’s cardiologists who had graduated from a medical school ranked in the top 25 of the 2018 U.S. News and World Report.
  • The “AMI Survival per real resource” (described in another paper by the researchers who developed it), which aims to capture productivity by dividing patients’ health outcomes by the resources devoted to them.

In using so many different measures, the researchers sought to rule out the possibility that their results were unwittingly capturing a relationship other than the one they sought to explore. In other words, it’s highly unlikely that the hospitals deemed “low quality” across the board in the researchers’ measures are simply those with sicker patients, for example.

“We don’t want to keep having this facile argument that high prices are high just because hospitals are getting extra profits they shouldn’t get—as opposed to recognizing that hospitals are making investments to attract patients.”

— Craig Garthwaite

“We look at a wide range of quality measures, some of which are dependent on outcomes and some of which are not,” Starc explains. “For example, we look at risk-adjusted mortality for heart attack, and we also look at technology adoption. In the latter case, the type of patient doesn’t matter—just, did you invest in this fancy machine or not.”

The researchers’ results confirmed their hypothesis with even greater consistency than they’d expected: Hospitals with higher shares of potential private patients consistently demonstrated higher quality in all measures. And the reverse was also true among hospitals that drew mostly publicly insured patients. The researchers estimate that with every standard-deviation increase in a hospital’s predicted nonprivate patient share, mortality increased by 1.5 percent.

“Consistently what we see is that places that have more opportunity to earn money from quality make costly investments in quality,” Garthwaite says.

To help verify that this increased quality was due to investments, the team next dug into hospital accounting margins, as documented in Medicare Hospital Cost Reports. They pulled two measures from the reports: a Medicare accounting margin, which captured a hospital’s fee-for-service Medicare business, and a non-Medicare accounting margin, which captured all other business.

They hypothesized that hospitals whose expected patients were largely privately insured would have both narrower Medicare accounting margins—since the cost of providing care would be higher for hospitals that had made large investments in quality—and higher prices paid by private payers—which helped offset the cost of the hospitals’ investments. While the prices might be different depending on a patient’s insurance type, hospitals were required to deliver the same quality of care, regardless.This is exactly what they found, suggesting that hospitals expecting to serve more privately insured patients were more likely to make big investments toward the quality of their offerings.

A Question of Trade-offs

Garthwaite says he and his coauthors chose to tackle this particular project because they believe it’s important to be clear-eyed about the potential impacts of legislation that would transform healthcare markets.

“I don’t think that our paper says that we shouldn’t have ‘Medicare for all,’” he says. “But it does suggest that as part of the conversation about regulated prices, we should be talking about this quality trade-off more than I think is currently happening in the policy debate.”

A natural question follows: How would hospitals change—and what quality trade-offs might they make—if legislation to regulate prices or significantly expand Medicare were enacted?

“It’s very hard to answer questions like, ‘What are they going to cut back on first?’ or, ‘How big is the quality effect?’” Starc says. “I don’t think we know. I do think we have a sense from this paper that, directionally, it’s not zero. If you turn off these incentives to invest in quality, there will be some change.”

Featured Faculty

Professor of Strategy; Herman Smith Research Professor in Hospital and Health Services Management; Director of Healthcare at Kellogg

Member of the Strategy Department from 2013 to 2021

Associate Professor of Strategy

About the Writer

Katie Gilbert is a freelance writer in Philadelphia.

About the Research

Garthwaite, Craig, Christopher Ody, and Amanda Starc. 2021. “Endogenous Quality Investments in the U.S. Hospital Market.” Working paper.

Read the original

Most Popular This Week
  1. One Key to a Happy Marriage? A Joint Bank Account.
    Merging finances helps newlyweds align their financial goals and avoid scorekeeping.
    married couple standing at bank teller's window
  2. Take 5: Yikes! When Unintended Consequences Strike
    Good intentions don’t always mean good results. Here’s why humility, and a lot of monitoring, are so important when making big changes.
    People pass an e-cigarette billboard
  3. How Are Black–White Biracial People Perceived in Terms of Race?
    Understanding the answer—and why black and white Americans may percieve biracial people differently—is increasingly important in a multiracial society.
    How are biracial people perceived in terms of race
  4. Will AI Eventually Replace Doctors?
    Maybe not entirely. But the doctor–patient relationship is likely to change dramatically.
    doctors offices in small nodules
  5. Entrepreneurship Through Acquisition Is Still Entrepreneurship
    ETA is one of the fastest-growing paths to entrepreneurship. Here's how to think about it.
    An entrepreneur strides toward a business for sale.
  6. Take 5: Research-Backed Tips for Scheduling Your Day
    Kellogg faculty offer ideas for working smarter and not harder.
    A to-do list with easy and hard tasks
  7. How to Manage a Disengaged Employee—and Get Them Excited about Work Again
    Don’t give up on checked-out team members. Try these strategies instead.
    CEO cheering on team with pom-poms
  8. Which Form of Government Is Best?
    Democracies may not outlast dictatorships, but they adapt better.
    Is democracy the best form of government?
  9. What Went Wrong at AIG?
    Unpacking the insurance giant's collapse during the 2008 financial crisis.
    What went wrong during the AIG financial crisis?
  10. The Appeal of Handmade in an Era of Automation
    This excerpt from the book “The Power of Human" explains why we continue to equate human effort with value.
    person, robot, and elephant make still life drawing.
  11. 2 Factors Will Determine How Much AI Transforms Our Economy
    They’ll also dictate how workers stand to fare.
    robot waiter serves couple in restaurant
  12. When Do Open Borders Make Economic Sense?
    A new study provides a window into the logic behind various immigration policies.
    How immigration affects the economy depends on taxation and worker skills.
  13. Why Do Some People Succeed after Failing, While Others Continue to Flounder?
    A new study dispels some of the mystery behind success after failure.
    Scientists build a staircase from paper
  14. Sitting Near a High-Performer Can Make You Better at Your Job
    “Spillover” from certain coworkers can boost our productivity—or jeopardize our employment.
    The spillover effect in offices impacts workers in close physical proximity.
  15. How the Wormhole Decade (2000–2010) Changed the World
    Five implications no one can afford to ignore.
    The rise of the internet resulted in a global culture shift that changed the world.
  16. What’s at Stake in the Debt-Ceiling Standoff?
    Defaulting would be an unmitigated disaster, quickly felt by ordinary Americans.
    two groups of politicians negotiate while dangling upside down from the ceiling of a room
  17. What Happens to Worker Productivity after a Minimum Wage Increase?
    A pay raise boosts productivity for some—but the impact on the bottom line is more complicated.
    employees unload pallets from a truck using hand carts
  18. Immigrants to the U.S. Create More Jobs than They Take
    A new study finds that immigrants are far more likely to found companies—both large and small—than native-born Americans.
    Immigrant CEO welcomes new hires
  19. How Has Marketing Changed over the Past Half-Century?
    Phil Kotler’s groundbreaking textbook came out 55 years ago. Sixteen editions later, he and coauthor Alexander Chernev discuss how big data, social media, and purpose-driven branding are moving the field forward.
    people in 1967 and 2022 react to advertising
  20. 3 Traits of Successful Market-Creating Entrepreneurs
    Creating a market isn’t for the faint of heart. But a dose of humility can go a long way.
    man standing on hilltop overlooking city
More in Healthcare